Friday, April 5, 2013

The Origin of Money and Coinage in Western Civilisation: The Case of Ancient Greece

A recent brouhaha has erupted over this article about the nature of coinage and its minting by the state, which also cites a classic article by Goodhart (1998; reprinted in Goodhart 2003). Libertarians like Robert Murphy are outraged.

While I do not agree with everything said in the original article, it does make the excellent point that coins seem to have been invented by ancient states to “pay soldiers … and then made … the only acceptable currency for paying taxes.” This, along with much other evidence, indicates that there is something wrong with the Mengerian account of money.

The whole debate raises three questions:
(1) what was Menger’s theory of money’s origins?
(2) how did coinage emerge in Western Civilisation in ancient Greece?
(3) did any kind of money exist in ancient Greece before coinage and what was its nature and extent?
I answer these questions below.

I. Menger’s Theory on the Origin of Money
We know people exchange goods for goods in spot transactions (barter). What happens when person A wants a good from person B, but the latter does not want the goods the former has to trade? This is the famous problem of the double coincidence of wants.

Menger notes that commodities have “different degrees of saleableness,” and that the thing we call money has a virtually unlimited saleableness (Menger 1892: 242–243). Yet the differences in degrees of saleableness apply to many other commodities. Many goods once bought cannot be sold again except at a loss (Menger 1892: 244).

But what to do with your excess goods once you have obtained what you immediately want in a barter exchange? What if you are unable to obtain what you want through a direct barter spot transaction? It makes sense for you to obtain goods with a high degree of saleableness, and then exchange these in the wider community at present or in the future. By this process, the most saleable good (or goods) becomes the physical medium of exchange (Menger 1892: 249).

Menger concludes that precious metals have arisen as a medium of exchange among many peoples because “their saleableness is far and away superior to that of all other commodities” (Menger 1892: 252).

Now it will not do to argue (as some internet Austrians do) that all a commodity requires before becoming money is to have a market value in some sense (such as occasional use as a normal barter good). That is not Menger’s argument.

In essence, Menger’s process requires the following steps:
(1) a world of significant barter spot trades;

(2) a commodity used significantly in barter spot trades attains a high degree of saleableness: that is, the proto-money commodity must be held and traded to a significant extent in the market;

(3) the proto-money commodity then emerges in the market as a real and actively exchanged medium of exchange to become money, the dominant good of “virtually unlimited saleableness.”
For Menger, money is, above all, a medium of exchange emerging from active and widespread market exchanges. The “unit of account” function of money arises secondarily from its medium of exchange role.

Apart from the fact that there are severe theoretical and empirical problems with Menger’s theory, which I describe here, does our empirical evidence from ancient Western civilisation confirm this in the case of ancient Greece?

II. Money before Coinage in ancient Greece
Coinage in ancient Greece appeared from 650 to 550 BC. But the question that any Austrian or libertarian defender of Menger’s theory of money would ask is this: was there some type of money before coins in Greece, and did it emerge by Menger’s barter spot trade process?

Before the age of Greek coinage, historians have identified certain goods which seem to have some of the functions of conventional money (but not all). But there was no identifiable metal money, or indeed identifiable money in the strict Mengerian sense.

In short, the state of affairs was this:
(1) cattle or oxen functioned as a largely abstract unit of account (but not a common medium of exchange) and
(2) iron spits might (or might not!) have been a very limited or weak medium of exchange.
Our important evidence for early Greek monetary history comes from the Homeric epics the Iliad and the Odyssey, which were written c. 750–700 BC, and reflect real social practices in the late Dark (or Geometric) Age from c. 1200–800 BC, and early Archaic period (800–480 BC).

In Homer’s epics, cattle or oxen are a type of unit of account, but the actual means of payment tend to be many other types of goods, not just cattle (Peacock 2011: 49–54).

Now one might argue that cattle did become the most common medium of exchange but then receded in importance to become a mere unit of account, but there are serious problems with this view.

First, the emergence of a “cattle/ox” unit of account in Greece appears to be related to religion and cult offerings, not emergence of cattle as the most saleable good (see below).

Secondly, cattle are of rather high value in an agrarian society but cannot be used for small transactions that are often the basis of trade. Cattle are not physically divisible into smaller units (and even conceptually this presents difficulties). Cattle are not always uniform or homogenous either, but come in different ages, breeds, degrees of health, and use. Nor are cattle durable, being mortal animals subject to age and disease, and hardly suited to be a long-term store of value. And finally cattle can be difficult to transport and hardly a very portable good (e.g., do you take one to market or travelling, if you want to buy things?). Will foreign merchants accept cattle for imported goods? What if your cattle run off?

Menger argues that metals are “far and away superior to that of all other commodities” (Menger 1892: 252) for use as money. Although the Greeks did have access to scarce metals such as gold, silver and copper, these do not appear as money in any accepted sense of that term in pre-Classical Greek history, even though the Greeks in private trade had centuries to select some metal as the reigning medium of exchange. But, instead, metal and bullion appear as just another barter good. Yet, according to Menger, metal is what we should expect to have emerged as money being the most saleable good.

So why an ox standard? While cattle no doubt had value in market trades, they were an important sacrificial animal and offering to the gods. The Greeks appear to have developed a cattle or ox unit of account derived from the value these animals had in ritual and sacrifice (Semenova 2011; Seaford 2004: 61; Einzig 1966: 372; Laum 1924). This thesis was put forward by the German scholar Bernhard Laum in Heiliges Geld: eine historische Untersuchung über den sakralen Ursprung des Geldes (1924), and has since won a great deal of acceptance from modern scholars (Semenova 2011: 381). Religious rituals and then temples had a preeminent place in the ancient Greek society, and the city government’s major responsibility was to honour, appease and placate the gods by offering sacrifices. In this sense, the ancient Greek temple and city are not separate entities, but really one and the same. So the emergence of an ox unit of account can be seen as another state-based, institutional process affecting economic life.

As we have seen, cattle seem unfitted under Mengerian theory to be a money commodity. But the ox acquired an importance over and above its mere agricultural use or commercial exchange value, because not only was it a crucial sacrificial animal, but also a means of payment for the services of priests (Semenova 2011: 385).

Priests needed to be paid in cattle for religious services, but it was soon also necessary to calculate the ox-value of other commodities offered for payment to temples or for sacrifice in lieu of oxen (Semenova 2011: 385): hence people came to develop “prices” of other goods in terms of oxen, and an ox unit of account emerged (see Schaps 2004: 9–10; Laum 1924; Heidel 1926; Peacock 2011: 54–63; Peacock 2003–2004).

What has provided crucial evidence of the link is the correspondence between (1) numbers of oxen used in sacrifices and (2) the monetary value of goods in terms of oxen as described in Homeric texts:
“what is so peculiar about Homeric valuation of things in terms of cattle (‘worth a hundred cattle,’ ‘worth ninety cattle’) is the correspondence between the numbers of cattle quoted as the value of various objects to the numbers of cattle sacrificed in Homeric sacrificial rituals (Seaford 2004: 61). More specifically, the numbers of oxen sacrificed are usually hundred, twenty, twelve, nine, four and one. But these units are also the customary units of value in the Iliad and Odyssey (Einzig [1949] 1966: 382; Seaford 2004: 61). This means that there is a distinct connection between the customized numbers of sacrificial victims and the specific quantities of oxen (the specific numbers of the ox-units) in terms of which the worth of various goods was estimated.” (Semenova 2011: 385).
But oxen were not generally used as a physical medium of exchange: they did not emerge as a unit of account from being the most saleable commodity in real and widespread barter spot trades. This is not consistent with Menger’s theory.

Instead, other goods like items associated with sacrifice of oxen such as tripods, cauldrons, double-axes, and spits were used as a means of payment as well as other metal objects (Schaps 2004: 10), all of which were measured in a cattle unit of account. (As an aside, some early fines in Greek city states appear to have been payable in tripods and cauldrons too.) One must also recognise that pre-Classical Greece was a society where gift exchange was an important activity alongside commercial exchange. Some objects were high prestige goods functioning as “gifts” that were neither traded nor “consumed”; instead, gifts were stored and then offered again to a new party as a gift.

What existed in pre-Classical Greece was an economy with an almost abstract unit of account where actual payment could, and usually was, made in many different kinds of goods through conventional barter exchange (and with gift exchange and debt/credit exchange in goods).

The second development of a type of possible proto-money alongside the cattle unit of value was the iron spit (or oboloi). Iron spits were employed to roast bull’s flesh in religious/state sacrificial meals and then used to distribute the meat to the public citizenry. Iron spits appear as dedications in Greek temples and tombs, but they might have had a very limited role as a proto-medium of exchange from the late 8th (or early 7th) to the 6th centuries BC (Seaford 2004: 103–104). But the trouble here is that they never seem to have acquired any universal or even significant medium of exchange value, and still seem to have been used alongside other commonly bartered objects like tripods and cauldrons (Schaps 2004: 85–88; Schaps concludes that spits were just used in barter trade). Spits were not useful for anything more than local barter, and probably useless for international or long-distance trade. Even on the most generous interpretation of the evidence, they can only have been a type of weak proto-money, which never emerged as a real “money thing.” And their religious or sacrificial use suggests a partial non-commercial source of their value anyway in temples, gift exchange, and bride price (Schaps 2004: 87); in other words, they could be a type of non-commercial money familiar from other cultures.

The Mengerian apologists might seize on these points and counter that none of these things discussed above are in fact money in their proper definition of that term; therefore Menger is not refuted. But that has the following consequence: the emergence of coinage is in fact the story of the origin of true money in ancient Greece.

Curiously, heterodox economists might agree that, strictly speaking, there was no widely-used physical good with all the threefold functions of money – as a medium of exchange, store of value, and unit of account – coalescing into a full-bodied money-thing in pre-Classical Greece. But, if one wants to argue this, again the consequences are quite clear:
“In sum, the Homeric world has no money-thing, that is, an object which answers to the description of money. Certain things perform certain functions, e.g., cattle (standard of value) and prestige objects (store of value) but neither performs the role of means of exchange or payment. Only in the Classical Period does a money-thing, coinage, come into existence.” (Peacock 2006: 642).
So what was the origin of coins?

III. The Origin of Coins
The first coins were minted in the second half of the 7th century BC (650–600) in what is now western Turkey (what was called “Asia Minor” by the Classical Greeks) in ancient Ionia and Lydia. Both the ancient writers Xenophanes (as cited in Pollux, Onom. 9.83) and Herodotus (Histories 1.94) report this.

These earliest coins consisted of stamped pieces of electrum with a roughly uniform weight in large numbers. Their value was large: about ten sheep. That is, they were of large denomination: perhaps worth more than 10 sheep and not useful for small transactions (Cook 1958: 260).

The scholar R.M. Cook long ago concluded that:
“From all this it may reasonably be inferred that coinage was invented to make a large number of uniform payments of considerable value in a portable and durable form, and that the person or authority making the payment was the king of Lydia. One solution suggests itself, that the purpose of coinage was the payment of mercenaries.” (Cook 1958: 261).
A reconstruction from the evidence is as follows: royal paymasters of mercenaries began to prepare electrum in lumps or shapes of uniform weight, instead of weighing out electrum pellets or dust as payment. Then the lumps were given uniform shape and marked with some sign and finally an official seal. Thus coins came into existence as the means for paying wages, but as a type of large pay packet for medium to long-term service (Cook 1958: 261).

At this point, the libertarian or Mengerian critic might question whether the earliest coins from Lydia were really minted by the state.

Glasner (1989: 30) contends that since these earliest coins had no names of Lydian kings “we can safely conclude that they were privately minted.” Yet that is a highly dubious argument. For a long time, coins did not carry writing at all, and there is no reason why the kings would have bothered to write their names on the coins when people at the time knew perfectly well that they had been minted by the state. Nor did early coins carry images of the living king: they mostly depicted gods, seals or other symbols. In Western civilization, one of the first kings to be depicted on coins was Alexander the Great in the 4th century BC, but centuries after coins had been invented.

Moreover, the evidence suggests that the Lydian kings either controlled the mines in their kingdom (Briant 2002: 400) or levied taxes on mining or extraction of metals (indeed a certain Lydian called Pythius under the later Persian empire, who owned a number of mines in Lydia, may have been a descendant of the Lydian royal family who had inherited these mines as private family property [Briant 2002: 401]), and it follows that, if they extracted and owned much of the silver, gold and electrum (panned from the rivers), it is most probable that the kings also minted the first electrum coins too.

Coinage spread to mainland Greece around 575 to 550 BC (or the second quarter of the 6th century). The numismatist C. M. Kraay looked at a wider sample of evidence from the whole Greek world and concluded that,
“since most coinages were not exported, and since those that were exported were not among the earliest coinages, the original intention in striking coins was not to facilitate foreign trade, or to provide merchants with a means of purchasing goods or materials not available locally. …. We must conclude that coinage [sc. ancient Greece] was not devised to meet the needs of foreign trade, and that, in so far as it came to do so, this was a secondary development.” (Kraay 1964: 89).
In addition, it does not seem that coins were introduced to facilitate internal trade either, for most states lacked enough small denomination coinage or had no coinage at all, and coinage had originated in Asia Minor and Lydia in large denominations too large for daily and normal retail trade (Kraay 1964: 89).

Everywhere one finds coinage in the early Greek world it has the stamp of the public authority: the issuing government or city state (Kraay 1964: 89).

The purpose of issuing coins appears to be bound up with both government taxation and expenditure: on the one hand, demand for harbour dues, fines and penalties in law codes (as law became increasing public, not private), and taxes, and on the other hand spending of the state on pay to mercenaries or soldiers, salaries to state employees, festivals (both secular and religious) and expenditure on public works (for wages and materials used) (Kraay 1964: 89).

Previously, payments to and from the state may have been made in kind, but as economies become more complex this itself became inconvenient. What was needed was a standard unit of value.

Although bullion was a high prestige commodity, there is no convincing evidence that it functioned as a common medium of exchange before coinage, first because it was rare and secondly because it was not easily divisible into uniform and small enough amounts. What certain kinds of bullion or metal did provide was weight units. The monetary unit of classical Athens, for example, was the drachma. It seems to have emerged as a reformed weight unit – that is, a pre-monetary metal weight unit – used as a common standard for assessing tax payments in kind to the state (Horsmann 2000; von Reden 2002: 153).

The Lydian state first adopted large denomination coins to make payments to soldiers and demanded coins back in tax obligations, and in this manner that coin unit emerged as money. But notice how the process violates the standard Mengerian account of the origin of money: electrum was not already functioning as a common medium of exchange by having emerged as the most saleable commodity in the marketplace.

Before Lydian coinage, a metal like electrum was a high prestige object and was simply one of many goods used in conventional barter trades: there is no convincing evidence that it was the reigning medium of exchange (money) that had already emerged as the most saleable good in spot barter trades.

Instead, electrum was a high prestige commodity selected by the state, standardised and used as a form of payment as wages. Its subsequent rise in market trades on a significant, but still (compared to modern money) limited scale as a common medium of exchange was then induced by the exchange of these coins for goods by soldiers, and the need to acquire the coins themselves to pay taxes. Prices for goods were created as a result of both the state payment of, and demand for, coins. That is, economies with previous barter, gift exchange and extensive debt/credit exchanges in kind were monetised by the state creation of coined money and the state demand for the coins, owing to taxes and other obligations (Peacock 2006: 644).

Furthermore, the earliest coins already seem to have been fiduciary to some extent, in the sense that the conventional (or nominal) value could be somewhat higher than their intrinsic value (Peacock 2006: 643, citing Price 1983: 5 and Wallace 1987: 393). People tended to count coins, not weigh them out (Peacock 2006: 643). What provided the major inducement for acceptance of official, stamped coins was the demand for them to pay taxes, fines and obligations to the state.

Another telling factor is that in many Greek states coins appear to have largely stayed within their national or city state boundaries (Kraay 1964: 90), because this was where the major demand for coins was: again both from the state itself and from citizens and non-citizens having to pay obligations to the state. Curiously, the one of two exceptions was the Athenian silver coinage, which became a type of international reserve currency by the 5th century BC, but because of (1) the overwhelming military and imperial power of classical Athens with its overseas empire and exaction of taxes and tribute from its allies and subject states and (2) the sheer good fortune that Athens was blessed with very productive silver mines.

In general, even by the 6th and 5th centuries BC numismatists have noticed that few areas of the Greek world seem to have had sufficient, lower denomination stocks of coins to meet the ordinary requirements of daily trade and commerce (Kraay 1964: 88). The only exceptions are Athens, Aegina and Ionia, whose economies appear to have been monetised to a greater degree than elsewhere (Kraay 1964: 88; Kim 2002). More recent modification of Kraay’s thesis by Kagan (2006) and Kim (2001 and 2002) does not overturn his fundamental point (Kurke 1999: 8).

IV. Conclusion
In pre-Classical Greece, no definitive “money thing” is found. At most, we have, firstly, a good (cattle) which only partially fulfills the functions of money by being a unit of account, and secondly a good (iron spits) that might (even on the most generous view) have performed a proto-money function as a medium of exchange to a limited extent (but the evidence is weak and it may have been no more than another prestige good used in barter).

But if one denies that either of these were real money, then the origin of money in Western civilisation is the invention of coinage. And coinage was an invention of the state.

Advanced monetised economies developed as the demand for money expanded though the need to have coins to pay taxes and obligations. The state itself provided the money in payments to the community. While one can point to other cases where Menger’s theory might have some empirical support (a fact recognised even by the critical David Graeber [2011: 75]), this is not one of them. In this very important case, Menger’s theory has been tried and found wanting.

FURTHER READING
My list of posts on the origins of money are below:
“Debate on the Origin of Money,” August 25, 2012.

“The Origin of Money in the Digest of Justinian,” August 21, 2012.

“Alfred Mitchell Innes on the Credit Theory of Money,” March 24, 2012.

“A Note on Menger on the Nature and Origin of Money,” July 28, 2012.

“Philip Grierson on the Origin of Money,” March 21, 2012.

“Observations on Non-Commercial Money,” February 18, 2012.

“Money as a Unit of Account and its Origins,” February 11, 2012.

“Quiggin on the Origin of Money,” February 10, 2012.

“David Graeber on Debt and Money, Part 2,” February 9, 2012.

“David Graeber versus Robert Murphy: A Review,” January 24, 2012.

“David Graeber on the Origins of Money,” January 23, 2012.

“Bibliography on the Origins of Money,” January 19, 2012.

“Alla Semenova on the Origins of Money,” January 15, 2012.

“Mises on the Origin of Money,” January 12, 2012.

“The Origins of Money,” January 8, 2012.

“Menger on the Origin of Money,” January 5, 2012.

“Money as Debt,” December 26, 2011.

“David Graeber’s Response to Robert Murphy,” September 9, 2011.

“The Origin of Coinage in Ancient Greece,” April 29, 2011.


BIBLIOGRAPHY

Briant, Pierre. 2002. From Cyrus to Alexander: A History of the Persian Empire (trans. Peter T. Daniels). Eisenbraun, Winona Lake, In.

Cook, R.M. 1958. “Speculation on the Origins of Coinage,” Historia 7: 257–262.

Einzig, P. 1966 [1949]. Primitive Money in its Ethnological, Historical and Economic Aspects. Eyre and Spottiswoode, London.

Glasner, David. 1989. Free Banking and Monetary Reform. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Goodhart, C. A. E. 1998. “The Two Concepts of Money: Implications for the Analysis of Optimal Currency Areas,” European Journal of Political Economy 14.3: 407–432.

Goodhart, C. A. E. 2003. “Two Concepts of Money: Implications for the Analysis of Optimal Currency Areas,” in S. A. Bell and E. J. Nell (eds.), The State, the Market, and the Euro: Chartalism versus Metallism in the Theory of Money. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham. 1–25.

Graeber, D. 2011. Debt: The First 5,000 Years. Melville House, Brooklyn, N.Y.

Heidel, W. A. 1926. “Heiliges Geld, eine historische Untersuchung über den sakralen Ursprung des Geldes by Bernhard Laum” (Review), Classical Philology 21.2: 191–192.

Horsmann, G. 2000. “Athens Weg zur eigenen Währung: Der Zusammenhang der metrologischen Reform Solons mit der timokratischen,” Historia 49: 259–277.

Kagan, J. H. 2006. “Small Change and the Beginning of Coinage at Abdera,” in Peter van Alfen (ed.), Agoranomia: Studies in Money and Exchange Presented to John H. Kroll. The American Numismatic Society. New York. 49–60.

Kim, H. S. 2001. “Archaic Coinage as Evidence for the Use of Money,” in Andrew Meadows and Kirsty Shipton (eds.). Money and its Uses in the Ancient Greek World. Oxford University Press, Oxford. 7–21.

Kim, H. S. 2002. “Small Change and the Moneyed Economy,” in P. Cartledge, E. E. Cohen and L. Foxhall (eds.), Money, Labour and Land. Approaches to the Economies of Ancient Greece. Routledge, London and New York. 52–66.

Kurke, Leslie V. 1999. Coins, Bodies, Games, and Gold: The Politics of Meaning in Archaic Greece. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.

Kraay, C. M. 1964. “Hoards, Small Change and the Origin of Coinage,” Journal of Hellenic Studies 84: 76–91.

Kraay, Colin M. 1976. Archaic and Classical Greek Coins. University of California Press, Berkeley, Calif.

Kroll, J. 1998. “Silver in Solon’s Laws,” in R. Ashton and S. Hurter (eds.), Studies in Greek Numismatics in Memory of Martin Jessop Price. Spink, London. 225–232.

Laum, B. 1924. Heiliges Geld: eine historische Untersuchung über den sakralen Ursprung des Geldes. Mohr, Tübingen.

Martin, T. 1996. “Why Did the Greek Polis originally need Coins,” Historia 45: 257–283.

Menger, C. 1892. “On the Origin of Money,” Economic Journal 2: 238–255.

Peacock, M. S. 2003–2004. “State, Money, Catallaxy: Underlaboring for a Chartalist Theory of Money,” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 26.2: 205–225.

Peacock, M. S. 2006. “The Origins of Money in Ancient Greece: The Political Economy of Coinage and Exchange,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 30: 637–650.

Peacock, M. S. 2011. “The Political Economy of Homeric Society and the Origins of Money,” Contributions to Political Economy 30: 47–65.

Peacock, M S. 2013. “Accounting for Money: The Legal Presuppositions of Money and Accounting in Ancient Greece,” Business History 55.2: 280–301.

Price, M. J. 1983. “Thoughts on the Beginnings of Coinage,” in C. N. L. Brooke et al. (eds.), Studies in Numismatic Method Presented to Philip Grierson. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge and New York. 1–10.

Redish, A. 1992. “Coinage, Development of,” in P. Newman, M. Milgate and J. Eatwell (eds.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance (vol. 1). Macmillan, Basingstoke. 376–378.

Seaford, R. 2004. Money and the Early Greek Mind: Homer, Philosophy, Tragedy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Schaps, D. M. 2004. The Invention of Coinage and the Monetization of Ancient Greece. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor.

Schaps, D. M. 2008. “What Was Money in Ancient Greece?,” in W. V. Harris (ed.), The Monetary Systems of the Greeks and Romans. Oxford University Press, Oxford. 38-48.

Semenova, A. 2011. “Would You Barter With God? Why Holy Debts and not Profane Markets Created Money,” American Journal of Economics and Sociology 70.2: 376–400.

von Reden, S. 2002. “Money in the Ancient Economy: A Survey of Recent Research,” Klio 84.1: 141–174.

Wallace, R. 1987. “The Origin of Electrum Coinage,” American Journal of Archaeology 91: 385–397.

7 comments:

  1. Wonderful. Thanks for clearing up some misconceptions.

    ReplyDelete
  2. "Furthermore, the earliest coins already seem to have been fiduciary to some extent, in the sense that conventional (or nominal) value was less than their intrinsic value (Peacock 2006: 643, citing Price 1983: 5 and Wallace 1987: 393). People tended to count coins, not weigh them out (Peacock 2006: 643). What provided the major inducement for acceptance of official stamped coins was the demand for them to pay taxes, fines and obligations to the state."

    I was thinking along similar lines, basically that coinage might have represented a kind of materialistic 'deficit spending,' in which warring states, with limited wealth, leveraged their treasure reserves by mixing more precious metals with less precious ones. One could presumably test ancient coins for metal content, and then, what? Compare the values to records of market values at the time, maybe? Makes for some precarious research, especially given the disarray that was measurement standardization in ancient times, but it could be done.

    Another possibility is that, in some areas, the value of the coin was first fiat, or based on social convention, and only later, perhaps after some social transformation (war, perhaps, or increased inter-state interaction), did the coin's value correspond not with social convention but instead correspond with its metal content, or at least a combination of social convention and metal content (what Richard von Glahn, vis-a-vis China, calls 'theoretical cartalism, practical metalism,' although he might have taken that expression from someone else.)

    (By the way, Von Glahn's book 'Fortune of Fortune' is one of the best English language treatments of Chinese coinage and monetary policy; there's also Peng Xinwei's book, 'A Monetary History of China.' When I get the time, I'm going try to put together a bibliography of political economic writings on China on my blog.)

    But I think it has to be mixed with a consideration of the origination of credit relations, which Michael Hudson, and following him David Graeber, are trying to do.

    From one perspective, the question then becomes: if credit already existed, then why created coinage at all? Here's where, I think, R. M. Cook's explanation comes in: credit is for people you trust; coins are for people you don't, like, say, mercenaries (likewise, they don't trust you.)

    But then are we leaving, effectively, the realm of chartalist explanation? After all, mercenaries (often from other states, cultures, etc.) are presumably not rendering up taxes. They might not even spend the money in the kingdom from which they earn it.

    Or, again, maybe not. Maybe a chartalist explanation makes sense, insofar as the king/state/ etc. levies the coins from his populace, thereby inducing them to accept payments from mercenaries, or military elements more generally. In that way the cycle is completed.

    The paucity of more concrete evidence allows the mind to go on a kind of a priori romp, the volume of possibilities leaving a lot of space for one's prior assumptions, prejudices, etc. Still, the sheer abundance of coins globally discovered by archaeologists makes me confident, or at least optimistic, that more conclusive understanding can be reached.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Thanks for this comment.

      Some points:

      (1) The testing of ancient Greek and Roman coins (or indeed any ancient or medieval coins) is regularly done by numismatists.

      You find variable results:
      (1) some coins of fine quality with metal content equal to face value
      (2) coins of variable value
      (3) coins of debased value
      (4) debasement of coinage over time.

      The Romans, for example, debased their coinage from the second century AD onwards, yet no disaster happened and price levels seem still to have been stable until the third century.

      The hyperinflation of late 200s AD was induced by rapid loss of confidence in the coinage, after very severe military, external, and internal crises, wars, and political instability, just like Weimar Germany.

      ------

      (2) "Another possibility is that, in some areas, the value of the coin was first fiat, or based on social convention, and only later, "

      As far as know, the early coins -- just through the limitations of technology -- had quite variable metal content, far from pure, yet they were still accepted.

      Aristotle makes comments that seem to suggest a chartalist view of coins and money.

      Delete
  3. Thanks for this. As a classics minor and hellenophile, this made my day.

    ReplyDelete
  4. On a more modern note--still so sure Bitcoin will remain a "curiosity"?

    http://blockchain.info/charts/market-cap

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Bitcoin bubbles are neither interesting nor of much significance. They suggest the regression theorem is false but we already knew that:

      http://socialdemocracy21stcentury.blogspot.com/2013/04/bitcoin-is-no-great-mystery.html

      Delete
  5. http://en.m.wikipedia.org/wiki/Electrum

    Mind the part about seigniorage.

    ReplyDelete